THE LAW OF EASY MONEY: A 300 year old example of quantitative easing

Buttonwood’s Column
The Economist print edition

“If five hundred millions of paper had been of such advantage, five hundred millions additional would be of still greater advantage.” So Charles Mackay, author of Extraor-dinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds, described the “quantitative easing” tactics of the French regent and his economic adviser, John Law, at the time of the Mississippi bubble in the early 18th century. The Mississippi scheme was a precursor of modern attempts to reflate the economy with unorthodox policies. It is hard not to be struck by parallels with recent events.

Law was a brilliant mathematician who was friends with the Duke of Orleans, the Regent of the young King, Louis XV.

The finances of the French government were in a terrible mess. Law had the insight that economic activity could be boosted by the use of paper money which was not backed by gold and silver. He was well ahead of his time.

Establishing confidence in a new monetary system was the trickiest part, but Law had the benefit of working for an absolute monarchy which could decree that taxes should be paid in the form of notes issued by his new bank.

He also believed that France could use paper money to develop its colonial possessions. Hence the Mississippi scheme, under which Law created the Compagnie d’Occident to exploit trade opportunities in what is now the United States. The money raised from these share issues was used to repay the government’s debts, and on occasion, Law’s bank lent investors the money to buy shares.

Turn this into modern economic jargon and Law could be described as creating a stimulus package for French economic activity. But rather than rescuing sunset industries such as carmaking, Law was an early venture capitalist, financing the vast potential of the Mississippi delta.

The problem was that the delta was a mosquito-infested swamp. Even though the company had monopolies over things like tobacco, it had little chance of generating enough income to fund the dividends Law promised.

So, a vicious circle was created, in which a growing money supply was needed to bolster the share price of the Mississippi company, and a rising share price was needed to maintain confidence in the system of paper money. You can see parallels with recent times, in which money was lent on the back of rising asset prices, and higher prices gave banks the confidence to lend more money.

When the scheme faltered, Law resorted to a number of rescue packages, many of which have their echoes 300 years later. One was for the bank to guarantee to buy shares in the Mississippi company at a set price (think of the various government asset-purchase schemes today). Then, the company took over the bank, a rescue along the lines of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. Finally, there were restrictions on the amount of gold and silver that could be owned, something America tried in the 1930s.

All these rules failed and the scheme collapsed. Law was exiled and died in poverty. The French state’s finances stayed weak, helping trigger the 1789 revolution. The idea of a “fiat” currency was perceived to be the essence of recklessness for another two centuries and the link between money and gold was not fully abandoned until the 1970s, when the Bretton Woods system expired.

Of course, the parallels with today are not exact. Law’s system took just four years to collapse; today’s fiat money regime has been running for nearly 40 years, as the money supply growth has been less excessive this time. But one lesson from Law’s sorry tale endures: attempts to maintain asset prices above their fundamental value are eventually doomed to failure.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.

You may use these HTML tags and attributes: <a href="" title=""> <abbr title=""> <acronym title=""> <b> <blockquote cite=""> <cite> <code> <del datetime=""> <em> <i> <q cite=""> <strike> <strong>